THE POLITICS OF HRM:
WAITING FOR GODOT IN THE MOROCCAN CIVIL SERVICE[1]
Khadija Al-Arkoubi
(Al Akhawayn
University, Ifrane, Morocco)
Willy McCourt
(University of Manchester,
United Kingdom)
THE POLITICS OF HRM:
WAITING FOR GODOT IN THE MOROCCAN CIVIL SERVICE
ABSTRACT
This study illustrates the
fundamental importance of a political understanding in order to improve HRM in
both public and private organizations.
It complements studies that have found a statistical relationship between
public staff management and economic growth by presenting a case study of
Morocco, using the strategic human resource management (SHRM) model as a
framework.
There are several reasons why
HRM in the Moroccan civil service has stagnated, notably unfamiliarity with HRM
models, and the French administrative heritage.
But the fundamental reason is Morocco’s political system, where real
power resides in the Palace, and where political actors are reluctant to take
bold initiatives. Thus a focus on the
management level is currently misplaced, and fundamental political action
harnessing the authority of the Palace without disempowering other political
actors is needed.
The study implies that a
political analysis is sometimes a prerequisite for improving HRM in both public
and private organizations.
Keywords
Strategic
HRM, international HRM, employee selection, performance management, Morocco,
civil service, political will
INTRODUCTION: GROWTH, GOVERNANCE AND HUMAN RESOURCE
MANAGEMENT
By now most
HR scholars are familiar with the bold contention that the way organizations
manage their staff can improve their performance (Becker and Gerhart, 1996;
Guest, 1997; Huselid, 1995). But in
another scholarly quarter, an even bolder contention has emerged, one that we
seek to explore in this article: that the way governments manage their public
servants can improve the performance of an entire national economy. It goes against what was until recently the
received wisdom. Throughout the 1980s
and well into the 1990s, the hugely influential IMF and World Bank had
promulgated the view that governments hindered rather than helped economic
growth - ‘No government or little government was better than big government’,
as one of the World Bank’s staff put it (Chaudhry, 1994: 199) – and they had consequently
exhorted their sovereign clients in the developing world to abandon grandiose
capital projects that crowded out private investment, stop wrapping investors
up in red tape, and so on.[i] But in the mid-1990s a more indulgent view
emerged. It contradicted the ‘minimal
state’ view by emphasizing positive actions like creating sound budgetary
institutions; the 1997 World Development Report (World Bank, 1997) was its
first substantial manifestation.
It was in
this changed policy context that researchers working under World Bank auspices
began to bring forward evidence of a positive connection between governance and
growth. A 35-country study uncovered a
significant positive relationship between merit-based selection of civil
servants (which WDR 1997 had also
emphasized) along with rewarding, predictable career progression on the one
hand, and growth on the other (Evans and Rauch, 1999; Rauch and Evans,
2000). A little later, Kaufmann and
Kraay, using a new 175-country dataset and different definitions, agreed with
Evans and Rauch (Kaufmann et al.,
1999), although they went on to qualify their view by developing an explanation
of those economies which were growing but were governed badly (Kaufmann and
Kraay, 2002[ii]). There could, it seemed, be growth without
good governance. The message was that governments
should not rely on the rising tide of prosperity to lift the governance boat
but should take deliberate steps to improve governance.
Such
correlational, cross-sectional studies have methodological limitations that are
familiar to anyone who has followed the HRM-and-organizational-performance
debate. Their findings are broad rather
than deep, identifying patterns across a range of countries but not explaining
the character of any single country, even though we know that the outcomes of
government reform programmes depend on complex combinations of many factors,
almost none of which applies uniformly across countries (Campos and Esfahani,
2000: 222; Nelson, 1990; Whitehead, 1990). They stop short of understanding how
the relationship they have uncovered actually operates, making it hard to
extract policy prescriptions from them to offer to governments (though Kaufmann
and Kraay do make suggestions about promoting mechanisms for external accountability,
participatory voice and transparency as a way of dealing with the problem of
‘state capture’ by particular interest groups.)
Such limitations are evident when we consider Morocco, the subject of
this article, for which Evans and Rauch’s data is confined to a questionnaire
filled in by two unidentified ‘experts’, while Kaufmann and Kraay’s is based on
pre-existing survey data from the Economist Intelligence Unit, Freedom House
and the like.
We point
out these limitations not to dismiss the studies that we have just discussed,
but because we want to complement them.
Where those studies are broad, shallow and quantitative, ours is narrow,
deep and qualitative. Thus we hope that
our study will give an insight into how the relationship between effective
government and economic development actually works.
STRATEGIC HRM
We focus on
just one of the deliberate steps that governments can take: improving human
resource management. This is much the
same as Evans and Rauch’s focus, although narrower than Kaufmann and Kraay’s,
for whom government effectiveness was only one of five governance
elements. But whereas Evans and Rauch
went back to Weber (1968) for their model, implying that we have learnt nothing
about staff management since Weber left us in 1920, we have preferred to derive
ours from the body of work on human resource management (HRM) that has grown up
in the last fifty years, and in particular from the development of the
strategic HRM (SHRM) model. It gives an
account of how staff management contributes to achieving an organization’s
purposes (such as profitability where private companies are concerned), and we
have strong empirical evidence, subject to the usual methodological
limitations, that applying it does actually make a difference (Becker and
Gerhart, 1996; Delery and Doty, 1996; Guest, 1997; Huselid, 1995; Patterson et al., 1997; Tsui et al., 1997). HR
practitioners and scholars, a somewhat downtrodden sub-profession only 15 years
ago, have acquired a sudden self-confidence, reflected in a leading scholar’s
claim that the favoured HR practices have a universal validity (Pfeffer,
1998). Translating all this into the
language of governance, it offers governments a way to improve their
effectiveness, and in so doing achieve their overall purposes, including
facilitating economic development.
The SHRM Model
The SHRM
model is by now extensively documented on both sides of the Atlantic (seminal
texts include Beer et al., 1985;
Fombrun et al., 1984; and Guest,
1989). Despite its current competitors,
such as the so-called ‘resource-based view’ (Kamoche, 1996), we judge that it
remains the dominant normative model, given the powerful theoretical and
empirical support which it has obtained, and which we outline below. We have chosen to analyse selected features
of it in detail, rather than to attempt a more comprehensive but inevitably
superficial analysis.
While some
writers reject the idea of a monolithic model, distinguishing, for instance,
between ‘hard’ and ‘soft’ HRM (Storey, 1995) or ‘lean’ and ‘team’ production
(Appelbaum and Batt, 1994), there are several features on which most writers
agree. Probably chief among them is the
notion of strategic integration: ‘All definitions of human resource management
agree on one point: that there must be a link between a firm’s strategy and …
the human resource’ (Purcell, 1995: 63).
Strategic integration means aligning staff management systems with
organizations’ overall strategic objectives and with each other (Anthony et al., 1993; Becker and Gerhart, 1996;
Fombrun et al., 1984; Guest, 1989;
Wright and McMahan, 1992). While it has
emerged from the normative HR literature, there is some empirical support for
the implication that the whole is greater than the sum of the parts (Huselid,
1995; Macduffie, 1995). Indeed Becker
and Gerhart (1996) suggest in their review of the performance debate that it is
what they call the ‘strategic architecture’ rather than individual HR practices
that has a universal validity.
Strategic
integration implicitly changes the HR specialist’s relationship with line managers. The specialist is supposed to design the HR
systems that will align with strategic objectives, while the manager is
supposed to carry them out. Guest (1989:
51) observes that almost all writers say that HR must be managed by line
managers: ‘HRM is too important to be left to the personnel managers.’ Thus at
the strategic level we concentrate on the twin questions of ‘strategic
integration’ and ‘line manager ownership’ of HR.
Recruitment and Selection, and Performance
Management
We also address two HR
operational activities, employee selection and individual performance
management and appraisal. We have chosen
them because:
1. We have good evidence for
their effect on organizational performance.
The evidence for employee selection is particularly robust (Schmidt and
Hunter, 1977). The evidence for
performance management is also robust, although oblique: it documents the
effect of objective setting and feedback on performance, both central features
of performance management (Walters, 1995).
2. Both are relevant to Evans
and Rauch’s research. Employee selection
is one of the two ‘Weberian’ elements on which they focus, and performance
management is implicit in their second element, predictable career progression. Moreover, we have seen already that WDR 1997 emphasized merit-based
selection, and it also appears in several of the surveys that Kaufmann and
Kraay draw on.
3. We know from previous
studies that there are substantial national differences in the practice of
performance management. Countries as far
apart as Denmark and Japan have resisted the Anglo Saxon model that focuses
exclusively on the individual’s performance (Brewster and Hegewisch, 1994; Love
et al., 1994; Milliman et al., 1998).
Readers who
are boggling at the apparent implication that the elaborate SHRM model and
associated HRM practices are widely applied, or even applicable, in developing
country governments should be reassured that the question of applicability is
one which our study explicitly poses.
THE
POLITICAL CONTEXT OF REFORM
Our case
study focuses on public staff management in one developing country. Why Morocco?
Firstly, because developing an effective public administration,
including staff management, in order to facilitate economic development is an
explicit aim of the government’s reform programme: ‘Morocco has undertaken
reforms to ensure sustained economic growth, macro-economic stability, opening
up to the global economy … Their success … is intimately linked to the quality
of the civil servants involved’ (Ministère de la Fonction Publique, 1998; see
also Proulx, 1999). Secondly, as a North
African middle-income country whose public administration is coloured by the
French colonial legacy, it is an interesting contrast with a previous study
carried out of Mauritius, a middle-income former British colony (McCourt and
Ramgutty-Wong, 2003), given that the Francophone/Anglophone divide is a major
fissure in post-colonial Africa.
Enduring Features of the Moroccan Political System
An
objective of our paper is to show how in Morocco, and arguably elsewhere, we
need to understand the underlying political system to make sense of or improve
public staff management, which in Morocco is becalmed by two settled features
of Morocco’s governance. The first is
the centralized yet disparate nature of government. Power in Morocco centres on the palace. In formal terms, the 1996 constitution
envisages a multiparty system of democracy, but also allows the king a lot of
executive leeway. He personally appoints
the Prime Minister, key central ministers and regional governors. While he often delegates his authority over
more junior appointments (including officials), the practical contrast with,
say, the British monarch, who also has the theoretical right to select the
Prime Minister, is stark. Moreover, the
late king Hassan did pass a strong legacy of skilful government in its own
terms to his son at his accession in 1999, whatever one’s misgivings about
certain aspects of it. Finally, even at
the start of the twenty-first century one should not underestimate the king’s baraka (roughly charisma), a
quasi-religious quality which derives from the monarch’s important religious
role[iii],
and which he shares with Muslim saints (Munson, 1993): the popular grief at the
death of King Hassan in 1999 attested to it.
But it is a
surprising fact that some have argued that the monarchy’s power essentially
consists of holding the ring between strong autonomous elites: the urban
bourgeoisie, including senior government officials; professors and intellectuals;
the army; and the rural notables (Clement, 1990). The model statement of this view is still
Waterbury’s (1970). For him, the king
was like a Nuer chief who, in Evans-Pritchard’s classic analysis (1940: see
especially 172-6) had little formal authority, and merely mediated between
tribes in the event of disputes, in a society where rebellion has been endemic
for much of its history[iv],
and which was held together, paradoxically enough, by opposition between its
‘segments’. In this view, the king finds
himself obliged to trim between and placate powerful rival groups. Some see Waterbury’s view as over-ingenious
(Eickelman, 1998; Gellner, 1981), but there is agreement that whether from a
position of strength or of weakness, the palace has played groups off against
each by the well-judged use of patronage, albeit the modernizing bent of both
the present king and his father means that recent recipients of patronage have
often been highly qualified technocrats (Joffe, 1988; Pennell, 2000; Tessler,
1987; Zartman, 1987).
The
Palace’s resort to patronage is an expression of Morocco’s deep-rooted
clientelism. While in other countries
favouritism relates to a single feature of identity, such as ethnicity in
Rwanda or religion in Northern Ireland, in Morocco it is ‘fluid’, to use
Gellner’s word (1981: 72): ‘Any individual … will seek a person who can help
him from any place in the country, any position in the official hierarchy and
on the basis of any personal connection that best serves his particular purpose
at that moment’ (Rosen, 1979: 53).
Individuals are thus reluctant to commit themselves irrevocably to any
single aspect of their identity, as that might preclude emphasizing another
aspect that might be to their advantage later on; and by extension, to nail
their colours to the mast of a single policy, as they might need to espouse a
different one later on.
Both
‘strong’ and ‘weak’ king views agree on some features of Morocco’s
politics. A positive feature is that,
within a stable system, political actors have developed the instinct to consult
and seek consensus: Morocco was a practitioner avant la lettre of what we have come to call ‘stakeholder politics’
(Hutton, 1995). The IMF stabilization
programme of 1983 illustrates this. In
the face of IMF pressure to adopt a rapid, not to say brutal approach to
reform, the Moroccan side entertained a wide range of opinions across
government, and even the IMF came to admit that the gradual pace of the reform
programme that emerged and the care taken to address the public’s anxieties
contributed to its success (Azam and Morrisson, 1994; Nsouli et al., 1995). Involving reform stakeholders has also been
central to the government’s administrative reform strategy, as we shall see.
However,
a negative feature, to which the particular character of Morocco’s clientelism
also contributes, is a tendency to passivity or attentisme in political actors, leading to an ‘abhorrence of bold
initiatives, and the overall stalemate that characterizes Moroccan politics’
(Waterbury, 1970: 8). Government is
fundamentally quietist, and does not so much take initiatives as arbitrate
between opposing interests when action is unavoidable, as in the stabilization
crisis of the early 1980s. Even the
dramatic ‘Green March’ which culminated in the ‘liberation’ of the Spanish
Sahara was arguably precipitated by the impending collapse of Fascism in Spain
(Pennell, 2000). This tendency, which
has deep roots in Morocco’s royal history, is compounded by the hostility to
innovation of the mainly conservative rural notables who are an important part of
the monarchy’s power base (Hammoudi, 1997; Leveau, 1985).
In
this analysis, royal intervention becomes the only way of overcoming political stalemate;
and, partly for this reason, other political actors have tended to accept it:
‘Everyone wants to believe in it, even when the sovereign’s decisions appear to
be guided by the interests of the monarchy and the social categories closest to
it’ (Hammoudi, 1997: 23). However, the
analysis is silent on whether, in the particular case of civil service reform,
that intervention will materialize or, rather, will resemble the ‘Godot’
character in Beckett’s play (1952) for whom the other characters are doomed to wait
in vain .
The Degree and Scope of Recent Changes
Now some
would object that while our account might have been true for most of the late
king’s reign, his last few years, when he deliberately smoothed the way for his
son, and the first few years of his son’s reign itself, have changed
everything. This brings us to the second
relevant feature of Morocco’s governance, the impact of recent dramatic changes
on a system that had been stable to the point of sclerosis.
At issue
here are the degree and the scope of change.
No one disputes that there have been real changes. Already in 1997 the general election had
ushered in Morocco’s first centre-left government, popularly known as ‘le
gouvernement de l’alternance’ (the government of the changeover), and the old
king had appointed respected opposition leader Abderrahmane Youssoufi as his
prime minister. The new king continued
the trend through symbolic actions like dismissing the powerful Minister of the
Interior, Driss Basri, and allowing longstanding opponents to return from
exile. Even Amnesty International,
previously critical of Morocco’s human rights record, welcomed the initial
changes, and has continued, with reservations, to welcome ensuing measures such
as the gradual release of political prisoners (Amnesty International, 1999 and
2002). Outside government, civil society
groups have mushroomed. Morocco with its semi-absolute monarchy is still one of
the most democratic régimes to be found between the Atlantic and the Persian
Gulf.
But how
profound have all the changes been?
After three years in office, the ‘gouvernement de l’alternance’
represented ‘a kind of continuity rather than a break with the past’
(Bouachrine, 2001: 10). Following the
2002 elections, as well as his usual quota of five key ministers, the king
appointed an unelected businessman and political neophyte as his prime
minister, picked faute de mieux when
the squabbling political parties failed to yield up a credible candidate. (It is important to note that recent
governments have been coalitions drawn from the plethora of political parties,
with all the problems of agreeing a common programme that bedevil coalitions
everywhere.) The new prime minister is
even more the creature of the palace than his predecessor, who at least had an
independent political base. The king
continues to chair the meetings of his ‘inner cabinet’ of appointed ministers,
at which all the big decisions are taken (Economist, 2002). According to one critic, even the
government’s privatization programme, which was proceeding and even
accelerating at the time of writing (Al-Hayat, 2002), has
become ensnared in the patronage game so as to strengthen the state’s links
with the commercial elite (Najem, 2001). Thus while we do not accept the cynical view
of one of our interviewees that the ‘gouvernement de l’alternance’ was
no more than a device ‘to facilitate the
transfer of power from the old king to his son’, we consider that recent
changes have been real, but not fundamental.
Every
manager will recognize the king’s dilemma in this somewhat changed context:
should I facilitate, ‘empowering’ and building up long-term capacity, or
command, getting things done today?
Morocco’s segmentary political system gives him the abiding temptation
to use his power to break the stalemate; the more so because the public, whose
confidence in its bickering and historically corrupt politicians is scant, has mostly
been happy for him to use it, even where it has served a particular royal
interest. But each time he does, he
confirms other political actors in their passivity and negates his espoused
commitment to democracy and a strong civil society. His uneasy solution, one that in the
Waterbury tradition is typical of the timidity of Moroccan political actors, is
to use his power sparingly and hesitantly, with the result that areas that are
not vital, or that are simply outside his field of vision (this is the issue of
the scope of change), have been left to stagnate. We shall suggest that government effectiveness,
including staff management, is one such area.
METHODOLOGY
We have
used a case study methodology for three reasons. First, it is especially appropriate to
research on government, since in the nature of things each country has only one
government to study, precluding the quantitative, multi-firm study that is the
staple of the SHRM/performance literature (Yin, 1994). Second, Becker and Gerhart’s review of that
literature calls for ‘deeper, qualitative research to complement the
large-scale, multiple firm studies that are available’ (1996: 796), a call that
Guest (1997) has echoed. Third, as noted
already, it complements the quantitative methodology used by Kaufmann and Kraay
and Evans and Rauch.
The case data
came from both primary and secondary sources.
Primary data gathering in 2001 and 2002 took the form of interviews and a
focus group meeting. Secondary data
comprised government reports and other documents, including the reports of two
workshops, organized by the Civil Service Ministry and by a trade union, and
the academic literature on Morocco.
Our main primary
data-gathering method was interviews with key stakeholders (Burgoyne,
1994). A semi-structured format (Lee,
1999) was used, based on the themes outlined in the previous section (strategic
integration, line manager ownership, employee selection and performance
management). Interviews were conducted
face-to-face and lasted from sixty to ninety minutes. The two authors conducted the interviews
jointly, with the exception of two interviews, which the first-named author
conducted alone.
A nonprobability
judgement sampling approach was used, targeting officials at the most senior
levels. Seven government officials were
selected for interview, identified by one of the authors, who is familiar with
the structure of the Moroccan civil service, as having a key responsibility for
the design and operation of HRM systems.
In two cases, officials were accompanied by two subordinates.
The following
officials were interviewed:
·
The secretary-general (i.e. the most senior official)
of a central ministry
·
A senior official with a central responsibility for
civil service reform
·
The Human Resource Directors of four Ministries
·
The director of the civil service training academy
In
addition, we interviewed a member of the national executive of one of the
largest trade unions representing civil servants, and an international
consultant based in Morocco who has conducted HRM projects with several
Ministries. We also conducted a mixed
gender focus group (Morgan, 1997) of junior civil servants from different
Ministries to give the point of view of a lower level in the hierarchy. The semi-structured format based on
identified themes was again used.
All but one
interview, and also the focus group meeting, were conducted in French[v],
and were taped and subsequently transcribed.
A content analysis was carried out in which interview transcripts, our own
interview notes and government reports and other documents were coded using the
themes previously identified.
FINDINGS
The picture
that we hope to paint is of a new government inheriting a stagnant, partly
corrupt administration leavened by some able technocrats in senior positions,
and relying on weak central authority and a standard but very slow-moving
reform model as a vehicle for change, while a few technical ministries have
moved ahead and introduced HRM initiatives of their own whose sustainability
and transferability, however, are in doubt.
The Civil Service
The civil service partakes of
the centralized yet disparate character of government as a whole. Hourani (1991) has observed how different
branches of government in Arab countries tend to become separate centres of power,
a tendency strengthened in Morocco by the French administrative heritage,
ironically consolidated by Morocco’s haste to develop its own administrative
procedures after independence when the French model was the only one available (Moussa,
1988; Snoussi, 2001). Morocco has reproduced intact the French system of
powerful professional corps, the
groups of engineers, lawyers etc., each with its own statut particulier, to which every senior civil servant belongs
(Rouban, 1999). Thus the corps of engineers, with its graduates
from élite institutions like the Ecole des Ponts et Chaussées in France, has
its own favourable pay and benefits which reinforce the separateness of the
Public Works Ministry where most of them work.
This has created a rather divisive ‘administrative feudalism’ (Marais,
1973) but it does give ministries some real autonomy. A second desirable consequence, augmented by
the monarchy’s technocratic bent, is that the senior civil service is
competent, as Evans and Rauch’s (2003) informants and Nsouli et al. (1995: 55) agree.
Another
aspect of the French influence is that Anglo-Saxon models of strategic
management and SHRM are not widely disseminated or practised in Francophone
countries (Barsoux and Lawrence, 1990).
Moreover, a system where officials identify with a technical corps undervalues management. One of our interviewees noted that line
managers tend to see themselves as technical experts rather than managers.
The French legacy also affects the role of the Ministry
of Finance and the Civil Service Ministry (CSM), the relevant central
agencies. As throughout the political
system, they have more power to block than to initiate. Budget approval for staffing decisions has to
come from Finance. CSM, the gatekeeper
of administrative law – its legal remit charges it with ‘ensuring the
application of the statut général of
the public service’ (Sbih, 1977) - is there mainly to confirm that decisions
conform with law and regulations, just as one would expect in a society where
what Hofstede (1980) called ‘uncertainty avoidance’ is high. Despite this cultural appropriateness, few
readers will be surprised to hear that line ministries do not particularly
appreciate CSM’s ‘finicky’[vi]
role (‘All that CSM and Finance are
interested in is following the regulations’), and we shall see that the
decision to locate the civil service reform programme in CSM has in fact
undermined its credibility and contributed to the inertia of reform.
Civil Service Reform
Improvements
to HRM stand or fall with the national administrative reform programme, which
has been the vehicle for introducing them.
The ‘gouvernement de l’alternance’ wanted to turn over a new
administrative leaf, aware that while there were able technocrats in senior
positions, the emphasis on patronage and security during most of the late
king’s reign, when the Ministry of the Interior was the paramount ministry,
meant that the civil service had stagnated, a view that a critical report from
the World Bank (1996) confirmed. The
government placed a small reform team in CSM and, following its customary
diagnosis and consultation, it launched a ‘Good Management Charter’ with three
elements: action against corruption, budget rationalization and improved
communication. The latter included three
HRM initiatives: staffing decisions should be based on merit, pay should be
based on equity and designed to motivate, and the workplace should be conducive
to productivity.
Some
actions duly followed. Civil servants
had to declare their property in order to identify people whose wealth had
corruptly increased. The government sold
off official vehicles and stopped paying water, electricity and telephone
charges in senior officials’ homes. It
also changed public procurement law and asked Ministries to take heed of press
criticisms and respond to citizens’ requests and complaints.
The aim of
the Charter was as much to raise awareness as to make concrete changes. CSM organized workshops at which the Charter
was presented, and ministries and representatives of overseas governments which
had introduced things like performance appraisal were invited to present to
ministries at large, the hope being that the latter would recognize the value
of the innovations and spontaneously adopt them. ‘Our
only power,’ said a central official,
‘Is the power to persuade.’
All these
were definitely steps in the right direction.
‘This is the first time that we
are talking about corruption in Morocco,’ said one senior official. Another declared that ‘Until now we've been thinking that administration represents authority
and power, but now we think that it should serve people and resolve their
problems.’ Moreover, rather than
resent the endless workshops, ‘tables
rondes’ and the like, some of our interviewees appreciated the attempt to
consult. But there were
difficulties. A central official closely
involved in the Charter urged us to ‘Go
now and ask about the destiny of this Charter.
People don’t even know what it is’.
When we took him at his word, we found that junior civil servants
did know about it but saw no sign of it being implemented: ‘We are good at studying problems and proposing solutions, but they are
rarely implemented. That’s why I haven’t
even bothered to see what’s in the Charter.’
The government had been unable even to take the simple step of
reducing the long French-style lunch break, even though a survey showed that
over 80% of staff favoured it.
Strategic Integration
We turn now
to the first of the HRM elements on which our study concentrates. In a word, there is virtually no evidence of
SHRM-style strategic integration in the civil service. There are favourable factors: the policies of
the new government could be the basis for strategy, piecemeal though they are;
there is some awareness of strategic management among central officials and in
some technical line ministries; and the relative autonomy of line ministries
makes it possible for them to develop their own strategies, as one of them was
at pains to point out. But one searches
in vain for the strategic elements: there is no HR strategy, and no conscious
attempt to link individual HR activities such as recruitment and selection to
an overall strategic plan which in any case does not exist (vertical
integration) or to each other (horizontal integration).
What goes
on instead is what ministries call ‘gestion courante’ or day-to-day management,
pretty much what Tyson and Fell (1986) called the ‘clerk of works’ model of
personnel administration. The more able
technical ministries, such as Finance, Housing and, Public Works have taken
professional initiatives, introducing computerized HR information systems or
performance appraisal. The less able
ministries see themselves as fighting, and sometimes losing, a battle to
maintain basic integrity, with a demoralized, partly corrupt HR function which
competent staff make it their business to get out of. Able and unable alike are pinned down by
personnel files. To get a civil servant
promoted, a ministry has to satisfy itself that there is a case, before
referring it first to CSM and then to Finance.
The whole thing takes up to three months, during which the anxious civil
servant bombards the ministry with requests for an update (‘you might have a couple of hundred a day’ said one official, using
dramatic exaggeration to make his point).
Line Management Ownership
Are
managers free to manage? Yes and
no. At the top, Morocco’s
‘administrative feudalism’ means that line ministries have more autonomy than
they do in Commonwealth countries like Mauritius (McCourt and Ramgutty-Wong,
2003), and some have taken advantage of it. But delegation to lower levels
within ministries is constrained by the central controls that we have already
discussed, and also by a tangible barrier (the high pay and education
differential between senior and junior staff) and an intangible one (Morocco is
probably high in ‘power distance’ [Hofstede, 1980], just like other Middle
Eastern countries and also France). It
is symptomatic that one of our informants said that ‘Your relationship with your boss determines everything.’ The same officials who grumble about
petty central controls impose them on their junior colleagues. Junior officials complained that even a
simple decision about permission to attend training might go all the way up to
the ministry’s secretary-general.
Recruitment and Selection
The
Moroccan constitution stipulates that ‘each Moroccan has the right of access,
in equal conditions, to civil service jobs’. Article Six of the Dahir, or royal decree, of February 24
which fleshes this out, states that the king, acting on the Minister’s
recommendation, appoints senior civil servants such as secretaries-general and
Chiefs of Police. The King and Ministers
have a great deal of discretion in how they do this, and ministers have
complete discretion to appoint whomever they like to their personal Cabinets.
Moreover, while the Palace and Ministers influence official appointments, there
is movement in the other direction too: the post of minister can turn out to be
the next rung on an official’s promotion ladder (El-Messaoudi, 1996). At less exalted levels, appointments have
been regulated since 1976 by a legal text, which specifies some criteria to
which all but the most senior appointments conform. That is why Claisse (1987: 53) says that ‘The
highest and lowest levels of administration reflect the most traditional forms
of patrimonialism whereas the intermediate level is evolving towards
modernization.’
Moreover,
just as patronage appointees can be competent, ‘merit’ appointees can be the
opposite. ‘Someone with a Master's degree in nuclear
studies may be recruited as an administrator.’ The state still plays the
role of employer of last resort to an extent, even though ‘Recruitment and promotion of people without the required
qualifications and training does not reflect commitment to reform. It is not
with these practices that we are going to reach performance and quality.’
In October
2000, the former Prime Minister used a circular to exhort his Ministers to make
key appointments on merit. How much notice did they take? These days, vacancies do get advertised,
examinations are administered, private recruitment agencies are engaged,
eventual appointments are made by a selection panel – sometimes. Such
initiatives by individual ministries taking advantage of the freer climate of
government are sporadic and not institutionalized,[vii]
and Ministers and senior officials continue to use and abuse their
discretion. We certainly do not have the
monolithic central civil service recruitment examination hankered after by
Evans and Rauch and by the World Bank (1997), which recently advised the
government to emulate the Commonwealth Public Service Commission model by
centralizing recruitment.
Performance Management
The civil
service law stipulates that civil servants should be appraised and graded every
year on their ‘professional knowledge, effectiveness and performance, and
behaviour’, criteria vague enough to leave appraisers plenty of room to
manoeuvre. The grade can affect salary,
but only at the margins. Reports, which
do not have to be discussed with their subjects, have to go to CSM and Finance,
like most things. Our interviewees
agreed that there is much effort for little return.
In other
developing countries such as Tanzania or Mauritius (McCourt, 1999; McCourt and
Ramgutty-Wong, 2003), that is where things have been left. But the Ministries
of Agriculture, Housing and Public Works have taken the initiative by
introducing orthodox performance appraisal. The reform team in CSM has pounced
on this initiative and, in its reform broker role (see below), has disseminated
it to other ministries. But it has two
limitations: it is not linked to any overall strategy, which in HRM practice is
essentially what distinguishes performance appraisal from performance
management, and it is not fully owned by government, reducing its chances of
spreading to other ministries or even of being sustained in the ministries that
have introduced it. Several informants
said that initiatives depended largely on individuals, so that progress could
come to a halt if that individual moved elsewhere, as happened when the dynamic
secretary-general of one ministry was transferred.
Civil service Pay and Employment
There is
one other important HRM issue which is outside our research framework. Observing that public sector wage bills
represent 12% of GDP (and 30% of government spending, as the Minister for the
Civil Service admitted in a recent TV interview), the World Bank (2000) called
for ‘resizing’ of the civil service to free resources for productive
investment. While, as is often the case,
a comparison with other countries in the region muddies the waters
(Schiavo-Campo et al., 1997), none of
our informants disputed the need to do something. As yet, action has been incoherent: the
former Prime Minister froze senior salaries pending a general pay review which
failed to materialize. The pay freeze
built up pressure, especially from the grands
corps. The government gave ground,
at some cost to its credibility.
DISCUSSION
The inadequacy of a management explanation
How can we
make sense of our findings? A
parsimonious explanation would be to see them through a management lens as an
instance of generic resistance to change (Kotter, 1979), a view which duly
emerged in our focus group discussion, one lending itself to the use of
standard techniques like force-field analysis to analyse change, as one of us
has done already (Al-Arkoubi, 1999).
Moreover, it was clear that current management approaches, including the
SHRM model which we focused on in our interviews, are not widely known. There is also scope for a management restructuring,
whether to delegate stifling administrative controls from Finance and MFP to
line ministries or even, moving in the opposite direction, to centralize
recruitment and selection as the World Bank has recommended.
But
pondering the role of CSM shows why a management explanation is
inadequate. As one of our interviewees
said, ‘We need to diagnose the Civil
Service Ministry itself … this Ministry is not appropriate to conduct reform.’ CSM is expected to drive reform, but we have
seen three reasons why it is weak. The
first is its role in the French tradition as the gatekeeper of administrative
law, which disposes it to assume that reform can proceed by administrative fiat (Proulx, 1999), and which makes it
all but despised by the line ministries, and by members of the grands corps, who tend to look down on
their administrative brethren, just as they do in France (Rouban, 1999). The second is the relative strength of the
line ministries, organised around their corps,
and centres of power in their own right.
The third is the deep-seated inclination of political actors to hold the
ring between opposing factions rather than to initiate, with the related
clientelistic preference for keeping every option open without committing
oneself irrevocably to any one.
All this is
reflected in how the government has discharged its reform mandate. Placing reform in CSM was arguably its first
mistake, tarring reform with CSM’s legalistic brush. (Sri Lanka corrected a similar mistake by
moving reform into the President’s Office, the strategic centre of government
[McCourt, 2001], though it is unclear where the strategic centre of Morocco’s
government might be located, if not in the Palace.) The government mitigated its mistake by
placing typically able technocrats in charge of the reform. The technocrats played a weak hand skilfully,
but also characteristically. The Good
Management Charter raised awareness of new but not over-ambitious approaches to
reform, which some ministries, who wield the real power in staff management,
moved to exploit. CSM then used its
central position to act as a broker of good practice, organizing workshops,
circulating newsletters and so on: ‘To
those who are lagging behind we say: Look what others are doing, try and
imitate them.’
But in
doing all this they lowered their own expectations of reform – ‘there are some modest reforms which are
also necessary’, as one of them put it.
Officials whom one might have expected to be champions of change talked
about ‘trying to be neutral, open to all
experiences’, and of ‘facilitating,
not saying: C’est moi, la réforme’. This was sensible in one way, but also
allowed them to keep their heads down in the way political actors in Morocco
like to do. It provoked the observation
from one of our interviewees that ‘the
file of civil service reform has been opened, but very timidly.’ More crucially, the observation was echoed in
a UNDP evaluation report that regretted that the programme ‘seems a little
timid to us’, and also, since ‘concrete results remain(ed) some way off’,
ultimately to the termination of UNDP’s support (Proulx, 1999: 8 and 41). It all boils down to that classic reform black
box, ‘political will’: ‘it is not so much
(a problem of) having models to apply but having capacity to change’ or, as another
interviewee put it neatly, not so much of ‘savoir faire’ as of ‘vouloir faire’.
In
a way, SHRM-style strategic integration is well suited to an assault on
Morocco’s ‘administrative feudalism’.
Surprisingly perhaps, it was a trade union official who made the point
most forcefully to us that a ‘holistic
and global’ approach to HRM would be an antidote to the multiplicity of corps and the piecemeal character of
reform initiatives to date. Moreover,
the fact that Morocco’s ministries have greater control over their staff than
their Commonwealth counterparts facilitates line manager ownership. But the sheer unfamiliarity of SHRM means
that introducing it would require a considerable slice of the government’s
limited political resources; and even then, the underlying problem of political
will would remain.
Thus we
judge that it is actually beside the point to recommend that Morocco should
adopt SHRM or indeed any specific management approach at the moment, because
any and every approach is likely to fall prey to the same timidity that has put
paid to attempts at reform over the last five years, with the danger of each
successive reform failure eroding the will of political actors. There is no harm in carrying on with modest
awareness-raising exercises which may bear fruit later on, but it is the
underlying political problem that needs to be solved before progress at the
management level will be feasible. This
is what we now address.
Political action as a prerequisite for management change
How to proceed in a system where no one wants to be the
first to jump? We suggest that the first
step is to reframe the problem in political rather than management terms as one
of overcoming political timidity and taking purposeful action, rather than of
adopting this or that management model.
Following from that, any action to address the problem must take account
of the need to recognize the fundamental reality of the primacy of the palace
while not exacerbating the timidity of other political actors by an arbitrary
royal fiat, something that we have seen the present king is in any case
reluctant to impose. A number of
approaches are possible. A first,
low-key approach might be to enhance the Civil Service Council, envisaged in
the Statut Général of the Civil
Service as long ago as 1958 but only convened for the first time in 2002. However, it
follows from our analysis that such an approach, which would not involve the
Palace would fail to overcome the inertia in the political system.
A more ambitious approach would be for reform advocates
to persuade the king to make a keynote speech setting up something like a
British Royal Commission, a committee of eminent people which would take
submissions from various quarters, including possibly from abroad. South Africa’s Presidential Commission for
the Transformation of the Public Service (Government of South Africa, 1998),
set up after the first democratic election, offers a model for such an
exercise. The Secretariat for such a
Commission, which would need to be in the Office of the Prime Minister or
possibly even the Palace itself rather than in CSM and which might include able
staff involved in recent initiatives, would over time evolve into an Office of
Public Service Reform, which while small should have greater resources than
those available to recent reform efforts.
The advantages of such an arrangement are that it
harnesses the authority of the Palace while not disempowering politicians and
officials; it allows the preferred consultative style to continue, in fact
extending it to Morocco’s energetic civil society, who could be represented on
the Commission and might supply a director of reform who is untainted by the
ingrained timidity of the civil service; and it might be possible to interest
an international donor in providing technical support. Moreover, one central official volunteered
something very like our Office of Reform proposal in an interview, though
without the Palace dimension. The
disadvantage, however, is that our arrangement could become merely the latest
talking shop. However, while a suitable
head and secretary for the Commission and progress-chasing arrangements would
reduce this danger, essentially one would be relying on the king to act in his
role of arbiter, for which Morocco’s history provides strong precedents, to
reconcile the different views and decide the way forward. This would be a political drama which,
contrary to all expectations, has a happy ending (unlike Beckett’s play!), with
Godot turning up in the final act in the form of a royal resolution of the
reform stalemate. However, the danger of
vesting so much in the whim of an individual, albeit a royal one, who has a
finite attention span will be obvious to most readers.
Lessons for HRM in
other countries
In the face of those like
Pfeffer who have suggested that favoured HRM practices are universally valid,
our study has found that they are not widely known let alone widely practised
in the government of Morocco, despite it being overwhelmingly Morocco’s biggest
employer and despite the abundance of able technocrats in senior
positions. This amplifies the finding of
an earlier study of Mauritius (McCourt and Ramgutty-Wong, 2003), since moving
from the Anglophone Commonwealth world of Mauritius to the Francophone world of
Morocco increases the intellectual distance from HRM practices, including of
course from the SHRM model on which our research interviews focused. Moreover, while we noted that such practices
would address real problems that at least some officials recognize, the effort
required to implant them would be misplaced, as it would be at the expense of
addressing the underlying problem of political timidity.
Every country is sui generis to a degree, but we suggest
that the importance of the relationship between HRM and the underlying
political dispensation is an intrinsic feature of HRM in the public sector,
even if its particular terms no doubt vary from country to country. Evidence for this comes in the ubiquity of
‘political will’ in World Bank evaluation reports as an explanation for the
failure of so many of the Bank’s civil service reform efforts (Nunberg, 1997),
and in public administration sources going all the way back to Caiden (1970).
Now of course a political
view of organizations is quite well established in work such as Child’s (1972)
or, slightly ironically, even that of Pfeffer (1992) himself, albeit not much
in evidence in the HRM literature. But
such work applies the notion of politics metaphorically to organizations,
treating them as if they were
political systems (Morgan, 1986). By
tracing a direct connection between a nation’s politics and the way its
government manages its staff, we are talking about politics in the literal
sense. Organizational politics, with all
the shifting alliances and conflicts of interests that Pfeffer and Morgan
discuss, is still only as big as the organization itself. The politics that influences HRM in a
government is as big as the society that the government presides over, and can
encompass, as in Morocco, a monarchy, a democratically elected government and
civil society. The implication is that
anyone hoping to influence HRM in the public sector, and possibly also any
senior HRM practitioner, necessarily becomes a political analyst. To make a difference, an understanding of
politics is every bit as important as an understanding of HRM itself.
CONCLUSION: THE POLITICS OF HRM
In
this paper we have tried to understand why one developing country, Morocco, has
made so little progress in improving the way it manages its public
servants. We have suggested that while
the SHRM model has some relevance to its problems, ignorance of the model means
that the effort of introducing it would be disproportionate, and would be at
the expense of tackling Morocco’s fundamental problem, the institutional
timidity of political actors which is not a personal failing but is a
consequence of the way in which Moroccan politics has evolved. Rejecting the Beckett-like fatalism into
which an analysis like ours might easily slide, we have suggested practical
steps that political actors might take in this unpromising situation.
Ultimately,
our analysis suggests that the elusive Monsieur Godot of civil service reform
and improvements in public human resource management is most likely to be found
lurking in the political undergrowth of reform, both in Morocco and
elsewhere. If we want staff management
to realize its potential and contribute to overall government objectives such
as economic development and poverty alleviation, as Evans and Rauch and
Kaufmann and Kraay have shown that it can do, or perhaps similarly to
profitability in the case of the private sector, then those of us whose
disciplinary expertise is in HRM will need to look beyond ‘universal’ models of
HRM and engage with political issues, both the metaphorical ones that we find
in private companies in industrialized countries and the literal and very
complex ones that we find in governments.
For more theory and case studies on: http://expertresearchers.blogspot.com
For Premium Academic and Professional Research: jumachris85@gmail.com
REFERENCES
Al-Arkoubi,
K. (1999) ‘Organizational change in Morocco: The case of human resource
management in the Ministry of Equipment’, Manchester: Institute for Development
Policy and Management, M.Sc. dissertation.
Al-Hayat
(2002) ‘New government accelerates privatization’, Al-Hayat, Rabat, November 14 2002.
Amnesty International (1999) Annual report 1999: Morocco and Western Sahara, http://www.amnesty.org/ailib/aireport/ar99/mde29.htm
(accessed March 8 2003).
Amnesty International (2002) Annual report 2002: Morocco and Western Sahara, http://web.amnesty.org/web/ar2002.nsf/mde/morocco!Open
(accessed March 8 2003).
Anthony, W., Perrewé, P. and Kacmar, K. (1993) Strategic Human Resource Management. Fort Worth, Tx: Dryden.
Appelbaum, E. and Batt, R. (1994) The New American Workplace: Transforming Work Systems in the United
States. Ithaca, NY: Cornell.
Azam,
J. and C. Morrisson (1994) The Political
Feasibility of Adjustment in Côte d’Ivoire and Morocco, Paris: OECD.
Barsoux, J. and P. Lawrence (1990) Management in France, London: Cassell.
Becker, B. and Gerhart, B. (1996) ‘The Impact of Human
Resource Management on Organizational Performance’, Academy of Management Journal, 39: 779-801.
Beckett, S. (1952) En attendant Godot, Paris: Editions de
Minuit.
Beer, M. et al. (1985) Human
Resource Management: A General Manager’s Perspective, New York: Free Press.
Bouachrine, T. (2001) ‘Peu de Réalisations
et Inflation de Discours’, Gazette du
Maroc, March 14, 2001: 10.
Brewster, C and
Hegewisch, A. (1994) Policy and Practice
in European Human Resource Management: The Price Waterhouse Cranfield Survey. London: Routledge.
Caiden, G. (1970) Administrative Reform, London: Allen
Lane.
Campos, J.
and H. Esfahani (2000) ‘Credible Commitment and Success with Public Enterprise
Reform’, World Development, 28:
221-243.
Chaudhry, S. (1994)
‘Selected Discussion Points’. In
Chaudhry, S., Reid, G. and Malik, W. (Eds) Civil
Service Reform in Latin America and the Caribbean. Washington,
D.C: World Bank, 199-202.
Child, J. (1972) ‘Organizational Structure, Environment and Performance: The Role
of Strategic Choice’, Sociology, 6: 1-22.
Claisse,
A. (1987) ‘Makhzen Traditions and Administrative Channels’, in W. Zartman (Ed.)
The Political Economy of Morocco, New
York: Praeger, 34-58.
Clement, J. (1990) ‘Maroc: Les Atouts
et les Défis de la Monarchie’, in B. Kodmani-Darwish (Ed.) Maghreb: Les Années de Transition, Paris: Masson, 59-93.
Delery, J. and Doty, D. (1996) ‘Modes of theorizing in strategic human
resource management: Tests of universalistic, contingency and configurational
performance predictions’, Academy of
Management Journal, 39: 802-35.
Economist
(2002) ‘The Palace and the Politicians: Morocco's Election’, The Economist, September 28, 2002.
Eickelman,
D. (1998) The Middle East and Central
Asia: An Anthropological Approach, Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
El-Messaoudi, A. (1996) ‘Le
Profil du Ministre Marocain au Début des Années 90’, Maghreb Review, 21: 77-94.
Evans, P. and J. Rauch (1997) Bureaucratic Structure and Economic Performance: Codebook 6/23/97, http://weber.ucsd.edu/~jrauch/webstate/website.out,
accessed March 19, 2003.
Evans-Pritchard, E. (1940) The Nuer: A Description of the Models of Livelihood and Political
Institutions of a Nilotic People, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Fombrun, C. Tichy, N. and Devanna, M. (1984) Strategic Human Resource Management, New
York: Wiley.
Gellner, E. (1981) Muslim
Societies, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Government of
South Africa (1998) Developing a
Culture of Good Governance: Report of the Presidential Review Commission on the
reform and transformation of the public service in South Africa, http://www.polity.org.za/html/govdocs/reports/presreview/, accessed April 7 2003.
Guest, D. (1989) ‘Personnel and HRM: Can you tell the
difference?’, Personnel Management, 21,
1: 48-51.
Guest, D. (1997) ‘Human Resource Management and Performance:
A Review and Research Agenda’, International
Journal of Human Resource Management, 8: 263-76.
Hammoudi, A. (1997) Master and disciple: The cultural
foundations of Moroccan authoritarianism, Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Hofstede, G. (1980) Culture’s
consequences: International
differences in work-related values, London: Sage.
Hourani, A. (1991) A History of the Arab Peoples, London:
Faber and Faber.
Huselid, M. (1995) ‘The Impact of Human Resource Management
Practices on Turnover, Productivity and Corporate Financial Performance’, Academy of Management Journal, 38:
635-70.
Hutton, W. (1995) The
State we’re in, London: Jonathan Cape.
Joffe, G. (1988) ‘Morocco:
Monarchy, Legitimacy and Succession’, Third
World Quarterly, 10, 1: 201-228.
Jones, D. (1973) Epoch
and artist: selected writings, London : Faber.
Kamoche, K. (1996) ‘Strategic human resource management
within a resource-capability view of the firm’, Journal of Management Studies, 33: 213-33.
Kaufmann, D. and A. Kraay Growth
without Governance, Washington D.C: World Bank, World Bank Research Working
Paper, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/
papers.cfm?abstract_id=316861, accessed April 8 2003.
Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay and P. Zoido-Lobaton (1999) Governance Matters, Washington D.C:
World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 2196.
Kotter, J. (1979) ‘Choosing Strategies for Change’, Harvard Business Review, March/April
1979.
Lee, T. (1999) Using
Qualitative Methods in Organizational Research, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Leveau, R.
(1985) Le fellah Marocain, défenseur du trône, Paris: Presses de la
fondation nationale des sciences politiques.
Love, K.,
Bishop R., Heinisch D., and Montei, M. (1994) ‘Selection Across two Cultures:
Adapting the Selection of American Assemblers to meet Japanese Job Performance
Demands’, Personnel Psychology, 47:
837‑846.
Macduffie,
J. (1995) ‘Human Resource Bundles and Manufacturing Performance: Organizational
Logic and Flexible Production Systems in the World auto Industry’ Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
48: 197-221.
Marais, O. (1973) ‘The Ruling Class in Morocco’, in I.
Zartman (Ed.) Man, State and Society in
the Contemporary Maghreb, London: Pall Mall, 181-200.
Mc
Court, W. (2001) ‘Finding a Way Forward
on Public Employment Reform: A Sri Lankan Case Study’, Asia Pacific Journal of Human Resources, 39, 1: 1-22.
McCourt, W.
and A. Ramgutty-Wong (2003) ‘Limits to Strategic HRM: The Case of the Mauritian
Civil Service’, International Journal of
Human Resource Management, 14: 1-19.
McCourt, W. and N. Sola (1999) ‘Using training to promote civil
service reform: A Tanzanian local government case study’, Public
Administration and Development, 19: 63-75.
Milliman,
J., Nason S., Gallagher E., Huo P., Von Glinow, M. and K. Lowe (1998) The
Impact of National Culture on Human Resource Management Practices: The Case of
Performance Appraisal. In S. Prasad
(Ed.) Advances in International
Comparative Management. Greenwich,
Conn: JAI Press, 157-83.
Ministère de la Fonction
Publique (1998) Résumé du rapport ,
Groupe d’Etude sur la gestion des Ressources Humaines, Rabat: Ministère de
la Fonction Publique.
Morgan, D. (1997) Focus
Groups as Qualitative Research, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Morgan, G. (1986) Images
of Organization, Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Moussa, F. (1988) ‘Existe-t-il
un Modèle Maghrébin d’Administration?’, in A. Claisse and J. Leca (eds) Le Grand Maghreb: Données Socio-politiques
et Facteurs d’Intégration des Etats du Maghreb, Paris: Economica. 148-72.
Munson, H. (1993) Religion
and Power in Morocco, New Haven: Yale.
Najem, T.
(2001) ‘Privatization and the State
in Morocco: Nominal Objectives and Problematic Realities’, Mediterranean
Politics,
6, 2: 51-67.
Nelson,
J. (Ed.) (1990) Economic
crisis and policy choice, Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.
Nsouli, S., S. Eken, K. Enders, V. Thai, J. Decressin and F.
Cartiligia (1995) Resilience and Growth
Through Sustained Adjustment: The Moroccan Experience, Washington: IMF,
Occasional Paper No. 117.
Nunberg, B.
(1997) Re-thinking Civil Service Reform:
An Agenda for Smart Government.
Washington, D.C: World Bank.
Patterson, M., West M., Lawthorn, R. and Nickell, S. (1997) The Impact of People Management Practices on
Business Performance. London:
Institute of Personnel and Development, Issues in People Management No. 22.
Pennell, C. (2000) Morocco
Since 1830, London: Hurst.
Pfeffer, J. (1998) The
Human Equation: Building Profits by Putting People First. Boston, Mass: Harvard Business School.
Pfeffer, J. (1992) Managing with Power: Politics and Influence in Organizations,
Boston, Mass: Harvard Business School Press.
Proulx, D. (1999) Programme National de Modernisation et
d’Amélioration des Capacités de Gestion de l’Administration, Rabat: UNDP.
Purcell, J. (1995) ‘Corporate Strategy and its Link with
Human Resource Management Strategy’ in J. Storey (Ed.) Human Resource Management: A Critical Text. London: Thomson, 63-86.
Rauch, J. and Evans, P. (2000) ‘Bureaucratic Structure and
Bureaucratic Performance in Less Developed Countries’, Journal of Public Economics, 75: 49-71.
Rosen, L. (1979) ‘Social Identity and Points of Attachment:
Approaches to Social Organization’, in C. Geertz, H. Geertz and L. Rosen Meaning and Order in Moroccan Society,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 19-122.
Rouban, L. (1999) ‘Senior Civil Servants in France’, in E.
Page and V. Wright (eds) Bureaucratic
Elites in Western European States: A Comparative Analysis of Top Officials,
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 65-89.
Sbih, M. (1977) Les Institutions Administratives du Maghreb,
Paris: Hachette.
Schiavo-Campo, S., G. de Tommaso and A. Mukherjee
(1997) An International Statistical
Survey of Government Employment and Wages, Washington, D.C: World Bank,
Policy Research Working Paper No. 1806.
Schmidt, F.
and Hunter, J. (1977) ‘Development of a General Solution to the Problem of
Validity Generalization’, Journal of
Applied Psychology 62: 529-40.
Snoussi, B. (2001) Les Grands Textes de la Fonction Publique,
Casablanca: Les Editions Maghrébines.
Storey, J. (1995) ‘Human Resource Management: Still Marching
on, or Marching out?’, in J. Storey (Ed.) Human
Resource Management: A Critical Text. London:
Thomson, 3-32.
Tessler, M. (1987) ‘Image and Reality in Moroccan Political
Economy’, in W. Zartman (Ed.) The
Political Economy of Morocco, New York: Praeger, 212-42.
Tsui, A., Pearce, J., Porter, L. and Tripoli, A. (1997)
‘Alternative Approaches to the Employee-Organization Relationship: Does
Investment in Employees Pay Off?’, Academy
of Management Journal, 40: 1089-1121.
Tyson, S. and A. Fell (1986) Evaluating the Personnel Function, London: Hutchinson.
Walters, M. (Ed.) (1995) The
Performance Management Handbook.
London: Institute of Personnel and Development.
Waterbury,
J. (1970) The Commander of the Faithful:
The Moroccan Political Elite - a Study in Segmented Politics, London :
Weidenfeld and Nicholson.
Weber, M. (1968) Economy and Society: An Outline of
Interpretive Sociology. Berkeley:
University of California.
Whitehead,
L. (1990) ‘Political Explanations of
Macroeconomic Management: A Survey’, World
Development, 18: 1133-1146.
Williamson,
J. (1993) ‘Democracy and the “Washington Consensus” ’, World Development, 21: 1329-36.
World Bank (1996) Growing faster, finding jobs:
Choices for Morocco, Washington D.C.: World Bank Middle East and North
Africa Economic Studies, http://www-wds.worldbank.org/servlet/WDS_IBank_Servlet?pcont=details&eid=000009265_3961214182006,
accessed July 1 2003.
World Bank (1997) World
Development Report 1997: The Changing Role of the State, New York: Oxford
University Press.
World Bank (2000) Morocco
in Brief, http://lnweb18.worldbank.org/mna/mena.nsf, accessed March 26
2003.
Wright, P. and McMahan, G. (1992) ‘Theoretical Perspectives
for Strategic Human Resource Management’, Journal
of Management, 18: 295-320.
Yin, R.
(1994) Case Study Research: Design and
Methods. London: Sage.
Zartman, W. (1987) ‘King Hassan’s new Morocco’, in W. Zartman
(Ed.) The Political Economy of Morocco,
New York: Praeger, 1-33.
[1] We
gratefully acknowledge the contributions of the government officials who agreed
to be interviewed for this study. The
authors can be contacted on k.alarkoubi@alakhawayn.ma
and willy.mccourt@man.ac.uk.
[i] The view to which we are
alluding is perhaps too well-known to require rehearsing here. Readers not familiar with its origins or the
policies to which it led can consult Williamson (1993).
[ii] Curiously, these papers
don’t reference Evans and Rauch’s research.
[iii] Similar claims were
still being made in Britain as recently as the start of the reign of the
current Queen, who remains the formal Head of the Church of England (Jones,
1973).
[iv] In Morocco’s case, this
view is enshrined in the French colonial distinction between the bilad al-siba (zone of rebellion) and
the bilad al-makhzan (zone of government)
(Pennell, 2000).
[v] Quotations from interviews
and from other French and Arabic sources are translated by the authors.
[vi] That is the word used in
a UNDP evaluation of the reform programme: see Proulx (1999: 41).
[vii] Staff reported that an
unanticipated consequence for those ministries that have improved their
practice is to raise the expectations of staff appointed, only to dash them
when the appointee comes face to face with the less glamorous reality of
Moroccan public administration.
No comments:
Post a Comment